TRUE RISK AND BEARER WATER BONDS (BWBs):
Why You Should Consider Adding Them to Your Portfolio
By Joseph Mark Haykov
This paper introduces Bearer Water Bonds (BWBs)—blockchain‑based tokens redeemable for FDA‑certified spring water at the source—as one of the lowest overall‑risk investments available today (when counterparty risk is considered). We compare BWBs to stocks, bonds, commodities, collectibles, and Treasury Inflation‑Protected Securities (TIPS), demonstrating how their unique structure combats inflationary erosion while offering tangible, resource‑backed value.
By investing in a finite, essential resource—natural spring water—and leveraging blockchain technology to minimize counterparty risk, BWBs offer a resilient strategy for preserving and growing real purchasing power.
This is not a securities offering. BWBs will be available exclusively to AML/KYC‑compliant investors, pending confirmation via a CFTC no‑action letter that they qualify as physical commodities rather than derivatives or swaps.
1. Introduction
In today’s complex financial landscape, it is more important than ever to understand not only where you invest, but also how you might lose value. Countless funds and “wrappers”—ranging from hedge funds to ETFs—present themselves as novel opportunities, yet they typically represent fractional ownership in the same core asset classes: equities, bonds, commodities, and real estate.
We begin by listing all existing core asset classes to illustrate how even the most sophisticated investment vehicles ultimately reduce to these foundational categories—because, in practice, no other real-world investment options exist. From there, we shift our focus to the concept of risk—not the short-term price fluctuations that preoccupy many investors, but the deeper notion of “true risk,” defined as the risk of losing purchasing power over time. Drawing on established theories (e.g., the Capital Asset Pricing Model and Fama/French frameworks) and economic principles (e.g., Akerlof’s “Market for Lemons” and the distortions associated with fiat currency), we identify four fundamental risks that every investor must navigate:
Counterparty Risk
Inflation Risk
Scarcity Risk
Demand Risk
Against this backdrop, we introduce Bearer Water Bonds (BWBs) as the lowest true‑risk investment option currently available, taking into account all of the risks outlined above. These bonds—similar to mineral‐rights contracts—are rooted in enforceable U.S. property law and are backed by a tangible, inelastic commodity: spring water certified by the FDA for human consumption and deliverable at the source. Fractional ownership is recorded via a improved (better, more secure) version of an ERC‑20 token implemented as a smart contract—a structure reminiscent of classic bearer bonds (famously depicted in the 1988 film Die Hard), where ownership depends solely on possession of the relevant private key, yet remains fully AML and KYC compliant.
By the end of this white paper, you will see how Bearer Water Bonds compare to traditionally “safe” assets—such as TIPS—across all four risk dimensions, offering a uniquely resilient mechanism for preserving and potentially growing real purchasing power. Ultimately, our aim is to move beyond nominal market fluctuations and superficial “low‑volatility” claims, emphasizing the enduring risks that affect long‑term purchasing power, including counterparty risk. Whether you consider yourself a conservative saver or an adventurous investor, understanding how Bearer Water Bonds function—and why they may outperform other “inflation‑protected” assets—could fundamentally reshape your approach to risk, resilience, and real‑asset investing in the modern era.
2. Major Investable Asset Classes
To properly assess investment risk, it is essential to distinguish between what can actually be owned and how ownership is structured—either directly (e.g., private ownership of a building in Manhattan) or indirectly (e.g., shares of a REIT holding that same building, listed on the NYSE). The following categories represent the fundamental asset classes, excluding fund structures, wrappers, or pegged tokens such as stablecoins. For example, stablecoins do not constitute a separate asset class; rather, they function like “digital ETFs,” representing fractional ownership of underlying M2 U.S. dollar reserves on a blockchain instead of existing autonomously like Bitcoin.
2.1. Businesses (Enterprises)
Typically Owned via Equities (Stocks)
Thanks to limited liability protection, businesses are often structured as LLPs (Limited Liability Partnerships) or LLCs (Limited Liability Companies). Ownership is typically represented by shares, which may be liquid depending on the circumstances:
Publicly Traded Shares:
Common and preferred stock in listed companies.Private Company Shares:
Ownership stakes in private ventures or startups, often funded by venture capital.
Note: Mutual funds, ETFs, hedge funds, and private equity funds are vehicles that hold equities, not distinct asset classes themselves.
2.2. Debt Securities (Bonds)
Government Bonds:
Treasury bonds, notes, and bills (U.S.), along with sovereign debt issued by other nations.Corporate Bonds:
Investment-grade and high-yield (junk) bonds issued by companies.Municipal Bonds:
Debt instruments issued by local or regional governments, often with tax advantages.Asset-Backed & Mortgage-Backed Securities:
Debt secured by pools of loans (e.g., auto loans, mortgages).
2.3. Cash and Cash Equivalents
(M2—Immediately Spendable Funds as Tracked by the Federal Reserve)
Bank Deposits:
Checking accounts, savings accounts, and certificates of deposit (CDs).Money Market Instruments:
Short-term debt securities (e.g., Treasury bills, commercial paper) offering high liquidity and minimal price volatility.
2.4. Real Estate
Residential:
Single-family homes, condominiums, and multifamily buildings.Commercial:
Office buildings, retail properties, warehouses, and hotels.Industrial:
Factories, manufacturing facilities, and distribution centers.Agricultural:
Farmland and ranches.Timberland:
Forested land managed for wood production.
Note: REITs (Real Estate Investment Trusts) are vehicles that own real property, not distinct asset classes themselves.
2.5. Commodities
(Held Physically or via Futures/Forwards; Prices Determined by Supply and Demand for Tangible Goods)
Energy:
Crude oil, natural gas, gasoline.Agricultural (“Softs”):
Wheat, corn, soybeans, coffee, sugar, etc.Industrial Metals:
Copper, aluminum, nickel, zinc.Precious Metals:
Silver, platinum, palladium, gold.
2.6. Collectibles and Luxury Items
Fine Art:
Paintings, sculptures, photography.Classic Cars:
Vintage or limited-edition automobiles.Rare Coins, Stamps, Antiques:
Valued for historical significance or scarcity.Wine, Whiskey, and Other Spirits:
Often stored for appreciation over time.Watches and Jewelry:
High-end brands and one-of-a-kind pieces.
2.7. Intangible Property
Intellectual Property (IP):
Patents, copyrights, trademarks (if directly owned).Licenses and Rights:
Broadcast spectrum, mineral extraction permits, etc.Goodwill / Brand:
Often inseparable from the business itself but can be distinctly valued in certain transactions.
2.8. Digital Assets (Unpegged)
Cryptocurrencies:
Bitcoin, Ethereum, and other non-stablecoin tokens whose market values depend on supply and demand—unlike stablecoins, which are pegged to fiat currencies gold or other assets.Non-Fungible Tokens (NFTs):
Digital art, collectibles, and in-game items (excluding “tokenized real-world assets” akin to stablecoins).Domain Names:
Often likened to digital “real estate.”
Note: Stablecoins are excluded because they represent claims on underlying fiat reserves, functioning more like digital ETFs than independent assets.
2.9. Derivatives (Not True Assets)
While derivatives (options, futures, forwards, swaps, structured notes) can be traded for speculation or hedging, they are contracts tied to the true price of an underlying asset—as opposed to being direct, standalone assets themselves.
However, when it comes to derivatives—especially in the futures markets—there is a nuance. Arbitrage, wherein one can either purchase the underlying asset immediately or arrange to have it delivered in the future, ensures that the futures price remains closely linked to the spot price of any asset (for example, the S&P 500 index or gold). In cases where the futures market is more liquid than the spot market, the futures price effectively determines the spot price through arbitrage. In other words, the cost-of-carry relationship ensures that there is only one "true" price for any underlying asset, as arbitrage forces the spot and futures prices into alignment. Regardless of whether you own the asset via futures contracts or directly—and regardless of which market is more liquid and thus determines the “true” price—you are, in reality, investing in a core asset, be it gold (a commodity) or equities in the case of the S&P 500.
Summary: Direct Ownership vs. Wrappers
Various financial instruments—such as stablecoins, hedge funds, futures, mutual funds, swaps, and ETFs—serve as vehicles for structuring ownership of real, underlying assets by holding portfolios of assets and fractionalizing their ownership. However, none of these instruments constitute separate asset classes in and of themselves. This list focuses on true investable assets in their direct form, recognizing that stablecoins and similar products primarily function like a money market fund (e.g., Tether is akin to fractional shares of M2 U.S. dollar funds). Independent assets—such as equities, real estate, or unpegged cryptocurrencies—exist autonomously and stand apart.
3. Inflation, Deflation, and the True Risk of Investments
Risk as the Loss of Purchasing Power
In investing, true risk—correctly and formally defined—is the probability of losing purchasing power. Most individuals require reliable short-term liquidity to cover recurring expenses such as rent, food, insurance, entertainment, and travel. As a result, they typically hold a portion of their savings in liquid assets. These assets must be highly liquid—essentially functioning as money—which means they include components of M2 (e.g., cash, checking accounts, or savings deposits) or longer-term bonds with coupon payments structured to cover recurring costs (for example, using bond interest to pay monthly rent).
For this reason, understanding inflation (a sustained rise in prices) and deflation (a sustained decline in prices) is singularly important when assessing investment risk. Inflation erodes the purchasing power of money over time, while deflation increases it. Both phenomena directly impact the real value of liquid assets and the ability of investors to meet their financial obligations.
What Are Inflation and Deflation?
Inflation is not merely about the price of a few items rising; it refers to a general increase in prices across the economy. Conversely, deflation is a broad decline in price levels. In effect, both phenomena represent changes in the “exchange rate” between real GDP and the effective money available for transactions.
The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics measures inflation using the Consumer Price Index (CPI), which tracks price changes in a basket of goods and services representative of the economy’s output (e.g., what the average family consumes). Two fundamental factors drive these broad price changes:
Real GDP – The total quantity of goods and services produced and consumed. This represents the size of the economy’s output (as approximated by the CPI’s basket of goods and services).
Money Supply (M2: U = S + E) – The total pool of potentially spendable funds. In our framework, M2 is divided into:
U (Total M2 Money Supply): The sum total of money available—such as cash, checking accounts, savings deposits, and other liquid holdings—as estimated by the Federal Reserve. This approximates the number of “money objects” (e.g., physical cash and immediately spendable bank balances) available at any given time.
E (Exchange Portion): The subset of M2 that is actively circulating as a medium of exchange (i.e., funds earmarked for near-term transactions, such as next month’s expenses).
S (Store-of-Value Portion): The subset of M2 held in savings rather than spent—akin to gold coins locked in a vault—serving primarily as a long-term store of purchasing power.
The U = S + E framework is not novel, it is just a formalization of Keynes’s concept of a liquidity trap—in which M2 is divided into funds actively used for transactions (E) and funds held as a store of value (S). This framework clarifies how shifts in the composition of the money supply can affect purchasing power.
Keynes’s Liquidity Trap
In 1936, economist John Maynard Keynes introduced the concept of a liquidity trap, a situation in which individuals and investors hoard liquid assets rather than spending or investing them. This occurs when returns on safe, short-term holdings (components of M2 such as cash, savings accounts, and money market funds) match or exceed those of riskier, longer-term assets (often classified as M3, including instruments like government bonds). With little incentive to take on additional risk, people treat money primarily as a store of value rather than as a medium of exchange, effectively removing it from economic circulation.
For example, instead of investing in bonds or businesses, individuals may hold onto cash or equivalents (like gold coins, as Keynes noted, or modern savings instruments). This behavior can paralyze monetary policy; even if central banks like the Federal Reserve lower interest rates to near zero, the increased money supply is hoarded rather than spent.
How Inflation or Deflation Occur
Under normal conditions (assuming we are not in a liquidity trap), a doubling of the overall price level—as indicated by the CPI—can arise from only two scenarios:
The Spendable Money Supply Doubles:
In other words, the amount of money being used for transactions (E) expands—either by shifting funds from S to E or through government issuance of additional M2 fiat money—while the quantity of goods remains constant. Under these conditions, prices will roughly double.Real GDP Drops by Half:
A severe drop in production and consumption—such as that caused by war or a natural disaster—could halve real GDP. For example, if half of a nation’s factories were destroyed, the economy would produce only half as many goods and services. Historical evidence shows that during wars, even with an unchanged gold money supply, prices can roughly double because goods become far scarcer.
In either case, prices adjust due to the balance between the money used in transactions and the quantity of goods available. Since real GDP—especially as represented by the CPI basket—is consumed at a relatively steady pace (e.g., routine grocery shopping or monthly rent), the only way to trigger broad inflation or deflation is by changing E relative to real GDP. In simple terms, more money chasing the same amount of goods leads to higher prices, and vice versa.
Ultimately, if consumption habits remain largely unchanged, whether money gains or loses purchasing power depends on the relationship between real GDP and the amount of money actively circulating (E). Any portion of M2 that remains in S does not directly influence current price levels, as it is not used for transactions.
An Accounting Identity for Transactional Funds
Traditionally, the Quantity Theory of Money is expressed as:
M×V=P×Y,
where:
M is the total money supply,
V is the velocity of money (the average number of times a unit of money is used for transactions),
P is the price level, and
Y is real output.
This equation is an identity that applies to the entire money supply. However, if we wish to focus on the funds that are actively used for transactions, we can define an effective velocity for the exchange portion, VE, such that:
E×VE=P×Y.
Here, VE captures the turnover rate of the exchange portion (E) of M2. The resulting accounting identity (as distinct from any quantity theory of money) demonstrates how the money actively used in transactions directly impacts price levels when combined with the effective velocity and real output.
Price-Level Changes vs. Investment Risk
This framework applies equally to inflation (rising price levels) and deflation (falling price levels)—both driven by the balance between the effective spendable money (E) and real GDP. In theory, a uniform change in overall prices does not inherently alter the relative pricing of different investments. For instance, if all prices double, the cost of a defense stock like Raytheon and a consumer electronics stock like Sony might both double; their relative values remain similar. The same holds true for sectors such as airlines, real estate investment trusts, and utilities—if every price moves in tandem, no particular investment gains an advantage solely due to inflation or deflation.
In practice, however, price changes are seldom uniform. Inflation or deflation can influence relative prices because some prices are “stickier” (slower to adjust) than others. Wages, for instance, tend to be sticky (they rarely drop quickly), whereas commodity prices like gasoline can change rapidly. This uneven adjustment—often called cross-sectional price volatility—can disrupt economic stability and adversely affect certain industries or groups. Consequently, central banks are wary of deflation (which can lead to falling wages and profits while debts remain unchanged) and aggressively combat high inflation (which can distort price signals).
From an investor’s perspective, deflation increases the purchasing power of cash equivalents, and bonds, since these assets gain value when prices fall. In other words, $100 in a deflationary environment buys more goods and services than before. Therefore, deflation is not generally viewed as a risk for holders of cash or government bonds. In fact, many investors equate “investing” with holding cash or bonds (considered safe assets) and, in their case, deflation benefits their purchasing power. The true risk for investors lies not in broad inflation or deflation per se, but in whether their investments can outpace inflation, thereby preserving or increasing their real purchasing power over time.
4. How Investments Generate Purchasing Power
In the real world, investments provide future purchasing power through one of two channels:
Selling the Asset:
Converting the asset into currency—or another liquid form—to realize its value.Holding the Asset and Living Off Its Income:
Collecting dividends, interest, or other ongoing cash flows generated by the asset.
This distinction naturally categorizes assets into two broad groups:
Non-Income-Generating Assets
These assets do not produce ongoing cash flows; thus, their purchasing power is unlocked only upon sale. Examples include commodities such as copper, natural gas, or gold. Although such assets can serve as stores of value, they may incur storage or transportation costs that can erode returns. In contrast, assets like bearer bonds, cash, and physical gold (e.g., gold bars or coins) generally do not carry the counterparty risk inherent in permissioned assets (such as equities or bank deposits), except in cases of direct theft. This lower counterparty risk is one reason they remain popular as stores of value. Notably, value investors like Warren Buffett have criticized gold for its lack of productive, real-world use—beyond serving as a hedge—since it generates no income, unlike assets such as farmland, which can produce revenue through crop production.
Income-Generating Assets
These assets produce regular income streams that can help offset holding costs and contribute to the accumulation of purchasing power over time. Common examples include:
Equities:
Businesses generate profits that may be distributed to shareholders as dividends or reinvested through share buybacks.Bonds and Fixed-Income Instruments:
These assets typically offer predetermined coupon payments, which tend to be more predictable than the variable dividends from common stocks.Real Estate:
Properties can generate rental income (for example, via platforms like Airbnb), although they may require active management. Real estate generally carries lower counterparty risk because ownership is held directly by the investor.
In mainstream financial theory, an asset’s total return is the sum of its income yield and its capital gains (or losses). For an investment to effectively preserve or enhance purchasing power over time, its total return must exceed the rate of inflation. Whether through regular income or capital appreciation realized upon sale, understanding how an asset contributes to purchasing power is key to evaluating its overall risk and return profile within a portfolio.
Understanding whether an asset generates consistent income or requires liquidation to unlock its value is essential for assessing its potential to maintain or grow your purchasing power over time. This insight enables a clearer evaluation of overall investment risk, guiding portfolio decisions in line with both theoretical models and empirical evidence from mainstream mathematical economics.
5. Price Determination: Scarcity and Subjective Value (Demand)
The exchange value (price) of any good or service is determined primarily by two fundamental factors:
Scarcity (Available Supply): The objective limitations on the quantity of the good.
Subjective Use Value (Perceived Utility): The degree of utility or satisfaction that consumers expect to gain from the good.
Drawing on Aristotle’s original distinction—later formalized in economic theory—“use value” refers to the inherent utility or satisfaction a product provides, while “exchange value” is the price at which it is traded in the market. In modern terms, the subjective valuation that individuals assign to a good is driven by its marginal utility—that is, the additional satisfaction obtained from consuming one more unit. This subjective value may be influenced by whether the good is:
Directly Consumed: For example, drinking whiskey for immediate satisfaction.
Used as an Intermediate Input: For example, a carpenter purchasing lumber to build a table, where the good contributes to the production of other goods.
This framework applies regardless of the asset’s income characteristics. Whether you own:
An Income-Generating Asset: Such as a business that produces goods or services.
A Non-Income-Generating Asset: Such as a luxury watch valued for its rarity and aesthetic appeal.
In both cases, the asset’s exchange value ultimately hinges on its scarcity (supply constraints) and the demand driven by its subjective valuation (the perceived marginal utility). This principle helps explain why certain assets—such as fine art—are inherently more volatile and riskier than, say, U.S. Treasury bonds. Fine art’s value relies heavily on fluctuating perceptions of utility and rarity, while Treasury bonds benefit from standardized, well-defined cash flows and lower uncertainty regarding their future benefits.
Price Fluctuations: Scarcity and Demand Risks
Even if the overall rate of inflation remains steady, the purchasing power of an individual investment can fluctuate markedly due to changes in its scarcity and the subjective demand for it. These risks emerge from two main dynamics:
Increased Supply (Decreased Scarcity):
When a good or service becomes more widely available, its scarcity diminishes, leading to a potential drop in its price. For instance, the development and production of high-quality, synthetic diamonds have increased the effective supply, thereby reducing the price premium typically associated with natural diamonds.Decline in Demand (Lower Perceived Marginal Utility):
Shifts in consumer preferences, technological obsolescence, or changes in social norms can reduce the perceived utility of a good. For example, as automobiles replaced horses as the primary mode of transport, the demand for horses—and consequently their price—declined. Similarly, smoking rates have dropped due to heightened health concerns, leading to a reduced market for tobacco products, even in the absence of a direct substitute.
Key Takeaway: Scarcity and Use-Value Risks
Scarcity and subjective use value are critical determinants of an asset’s price and, by extension, its risk profile. These dimensions influence an asset’s real value independently of general inflation. Investors must carefully weigh these factors—recognizing that even in an environment of stable inflation, changes in supply conditions or shifts in consumer preferences can lead to significant fluctuations in market value. Understanding these risks is essential for evaluating the stability and long-term viability of any investment.
6. Counterparty Risk
Counterparty risk represents a critical yet often underappreciated dimension of financial risk. While it is narrowly defined in legal contexts as the probability that a party in a financial transaction will fail to meet its contractual obligations, its practical implications extend much further in real-world investing. In economic terms, counterparty risk introduces the possibility that an investor may lose access to the benefits or ownership of an asset—even if the asset itself persists—due to legal, structural, or custodial failures (such as bankruptcy, operational breakdowns, or intermediary insolvency). Unlike market risks (e.g., inflation or demand shocks), which affect asset prices systemically, counterparty risk is strictly endogenous—arising from institutional fragility, misaligned incentives, and agency problems within the financial system.
Economic Foundations
Modern economic theory frames counterparty risk through the lenses of asymmetric information, strategic interaction, and incomplete contracting. Beyond simple default risk, it encompasses scenarios in which one party exploits informational advantages to the detriment of another, as illustrated by Akerlof’s The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism (1970). In this canonical model, asymmetric information between buyers and sellers generates adverse selection—a form of strategic uncertainty that distorts prices, reduces trade efficiency, and may even collapse markets. Such dynamics align with game-theoretic principles, where rational actors, anticipating counterparty opportunism, settle into suboptimal equilibria—for example, underinvestment in high-quality assets due to fear of opportunistic default.
Moreover, counterparty risk intersects with credit risk and operational risk, particularly in derivatives markets, repo agreements, and custodial relationships. Mitigation strategies often rely on mechanisms such as collateralization, centralized clearinghouses, and robust enforcement measures—all designed to align the interests of the parties involved and reduce moral hazard. While reputation-based incentives can influence behavior in repeated interactions, they are not sufficient on their own to mitigate counterparty risk, particularly in low-frequency financial relationships.
Common Examples of Counterparty Risk
Corporate Bankruptcy
When a firm goes bankrupt, bondholders might retain a claim on the firm's assets, but stockholders typically lose their equity entirely. Even bondholders may only recover a portion of their investment, often after lengthy and uncertain bankruptcy proceedings.
Broker Failure (e.g., Lehman Brothers, MF Global)
If a broker collapses, investors may temporarily or permanently lose access to their fractional ownership, even if the underlying asset remains intact. The collapse of Lehman Brothers in 2008 and MF Global in 2011 illustrate how mismanagement and inadequate segregation of client funds can lead to irreversible losses. In some jurisdictions (e.g., the U.S.), properly segregated client assets remain legally protected, meaning broker failure does not always result in investor losses. The true risk lies in rehypothecation, fraud, or regulatory loopholes.
Theft and Fraud
Physical assets (such as gold or artwork) can be stolen, and financial assets might be misappropriated by dishonest managers. High-profile cases like Bernie Madoff’s Ponzi scheme capture headlines, but smaller-scale thefts and mismanagement occur more frequently than many investors realize. In highly intermediated markets, counterparty fraud can be difficult to detect until it is too late.
Florida Hurricane Insurance Example
Consider how Florida’s hurricane season tests the resilience of insurance companies. Many insurers use reinsurance to diversify their risks. However, if several insurers are exposed to similar catastrophic losses due to hurricanes—and if these insurers share common risk exposures—the risk can become concentrated. In such cases, even if individual policies are sound, the failure of one insurer to meet its obligations (due to underpricing or mismanagement of hurricane risk) can trigger a chain reaction of losses. This example illustrates that diversification across insurers and geographic regions is essential; failing to do so can lead to systemic counterparty risk, much like excessive reliance on a single custodian in financial markets.
Why Counterparty Risk Is Overlooked
Many investors assume that “if the asset exists, I own it.” However, most real-world ownership structures—especially for publicly traded securities—rely on intermediaries such as brokers, custodians, or exchanges. If any link in this chain fails, the investor’s practical ability to claim, transfer, or sell the asset may be compromised. Additionally, global legal jurisdictions and opaque contractual agreements further obscure ownership rights. For example, a U.S. investor who purchased Sberbank ADRs through a U.S. brokerage before the Ukraine war ultimately lost their ownership stake, even though the underlying shares continue to trade in Moscow. (Note that this case involved sovereign intervention—a form of exogenous risk—highlighting the common confusion between counterparty risk and external shocks.)
Mitigating Counterparty Risk
Investors can reduce counterparty risk through several strategies:
Secure Storage and Custody
Physical Assets: Use insured vaults or professional custodians to minimize the risk of theft or fraud.
Digital Assets: Opt for hardware wallets or reputable non-custodial platforms to reduce exposure to exchange insolvency risks.
Reputable Intermediaries
Select well-capitalized, regulated brokers or banks with transparent balance sheets.
Prioritize institutions offering robust insurance protections, such as SIPC coverage for brokerage accounts or FDIC insurance for bank deposits.
Beware of excessive rehypothecation practices (repledging of collateral), as this can create systemic vulnerabilities.
Robust Legal Safeguards
Ensure contracts are clear and enforceable, with client funds held in segregated accounts to prevent creditor claims in bankruptcy.
Rely on legal recourse and additional insurance backstops to provide critical layers of protection should an intermediary fail.
Diversification of Custodians
Spread assets across multiple custodians or jurisdictions to avoid single-point failures.
True diversification requires choosing custodians that are structurally independent, not merely different in name.
(As seen in the 2008 financial crisis and more recently with crypto exchanges like FTX and Celsius, shared risk exposures can lead to systemic failures.)
Counterparty Risk vs. Acts of God
Counterparty risk is endogenous—stemming from financial fragility, strategic behavior, or institutional design flaws—and is insurable because it follows predictable probability distributions (e.g., credit default risk).
Acts of God, such as natural disasters, sovereign expropriation, or geopolitical interventions, are exogenous shocks with non-stationary, fat-tailed, or unknowable probabilities and are not insurable.
Example: The Lehman Brothers collapse was a case of counterparty risk (mispriced but hedgeable), whereas a nuclear war destroying financial systems would be an exogenous shock.
Counterparty risk underscores that true ownership is not merely about acquiring an asset—it is about maintaining a clear, enforceable claim to it. By recognizing and mitigating this endogenous risk through secure custody, reputable intermediaries, robust legal safeguards, and careful diversification, investors can better protect their assets. However, it is critical to distinguish between internal financial fragility and external, non-insurable shocks (Acts of God) for effective risk management.
7. Summary: Defining Investment Risk
Investment risk can be broadly categorized into two overarching types:
The Risk of Losing Purchasing Power
This category includes risks such as inflation, declining demand, or reduced scarcity—all of which erode an investment’s real value over time.The Risk of Losing Ownership
Even if an asset retains its inherent value, your ability to access or benefit from that asset may be compromised if legal, structural, or custodial failures occur.
Formal Definition of Investment Risk: Four Fundamental Types
Within these two categories, we identify four primary types of investment risk. These represent the fundamental real-world scenarios in which investors can lose purchasing power:
Counterparty Risk
This risk arises when another party’s actions prevent you from accessing or retaining ownership of an asset.
Examples:Theft of physical assets, such as gold.
Broker failure rendering your holdings inaccessible.
Inflation Risk
Excessive money printing, geopolitical events (such as war), or other inflationary pressures can erode the purchasing power of an investment over time.Scarcity Risk
A reduction in the scarcity of a product, service, or asset diminishes its value.
Example:Dexter Shoes lost market share due to an influx of cheaper imports, reducing the relative scarcity of quality footwear.
Demand Risk
A decline in demand—whether from shifts in consumer preferences or technological obsolescence—undermines an investment’s value.
Example:The transition from horse-drawn carriages to automobiles triggered a steep drop in demand for the former.
By understanding these four types of risk, investors can develop a comprehensive framework for identifying vulnerabilities in their capital. This framework reflects mainstream economic thinking, which recognizes that the true risk of an investment depends not only on general inflationary trends but also on specific, idiosyncratic factors such as changes in scarcity, demand, and counterparty stability.
The Scarcity and Demand Risk: Empirical Evidence
A review of the top 20 companies in the S&P 500 from 1995 to 2025 reveals a striking fact: only five companies appear on both lists. These are:
Exxon Mobil: (1995 #1, 2025 #15)
Microsoft: (1995 #9, 2025 #3)
Walmart: (1995 #8, 2025 #11)
Procter & Gamble: (1995 #6, 2025 #19)
Eli Lilly: (1995 #20, 2025 #10)
This indicates that only a few stocks managed to retain top-20 status over three decades. The companies that dropped out lost purchasing power relative to their peers—a change not explained solely by aggregate inflation or deflation. Instead, these shifts in market valuation primarily result from:
Shifting Supply (Scarcity):
Example: Loews declined partly because advancements in home-viewing technology reduced the need for movie theaters, lowering their scarcity and thus their value.Shifting Demand (Subjective Use-Value):
Example: Investment dollars and consumer spending increasingly flowed into technology rather than soft drinks, contributing to a relative downturn for companies like PepsiCo.
Beyond these factors—scarcity and demand risk—only two additional explanations remain for relative changes in S&P 500 rankings:
Counterparty Risk:
Cases of management fraud (e.g., Enron, WorldCom) are prime examples.Acts of God:
While uninsured losses (e.g., from fire or natural disasters) might be classified as acts of God, modern insurance typically mitigates these risks. If insurance fails or is absent (perhaps due to a breach of fiduciary duty), the resulting loss effectively becomes counterparty risk.
In a modern economy, with widespread insurance and robust legal safeguards, acts of God represent only a minor tail risk. Empirical evidence suggests that when companies fail due to so-called “tail risks,” the underlying issues often boil down to counterparty risk—illustrated by cases like Theranos, Enron, and other fraud incidents.
Price Volatility as an Estimate of True Risk
Price volatility is frequently used as a proxy for true investment risk. The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) posits that only systematic (market or sector) volatility is rewarded with higher returns, as diversifiable (idiosyncratic) risk should be arbitraged away in efficient markets. Two key points are worth noting:
Volatility as a Risk Proxy:
Under an ideal, unfettered market, price volatility accurately reflects risk. However, in a fiat money system, factors such as regulatory interventions or central bank policies may cause deviations from this ideal.Competition-Driven Volatility:
Volatility often arises when superior or lower-cost competitors enter the market. For example, Dexter Shoes was driven out of business by cheaper imported shoes—a clear case of how competitive dynamics can erode market share and induce price volatility.
Moreover, scarcity is not static. Factors that influence scarcity include:
Natural Limits: Finite resources (e.g., oil, lithium).
Production Costs: Rising labor, energy, or material costs that reduce supply (e.g., semiconductor shortages during COVID-19).
Artificial Manipulation: Actions by cartels (e.g., OPEC), patent protections, or strategic stockpiling (e.g., De Beers and diamonds).
Regulation: Bans, quotas, or tariffs (e.g., EU restrictions on rare earth mineral exports).
Subjective use-value, meanwhile, reflects human preferences that can be rational, irrational, or speculative. Examples include:
Functional Utility: The practical value of a hammer to a carpenter.
Emotional/Cultural Value: A Rolex watch as a status symbol.
Speculative Demand: Cryptocurrencies valued for anticipated future scarcity.
Behavioral Biases: Phenomena such as FOMO (fear of missing out) that drive meme stock frenzies.
Ultimately, an asset’s ability to sustain exclusivity and demand—through factors like brand equity, copyrights, trademarks, or other forms of goodwill—determines its true risk. A “moat” around a business, as Warren Buffett emphasizes, helps protect an asset’s value from competitive pressures. In contrast, “moatless” investments tend to be riskier and more volatile.
A more detailed exploration of volatility as a nuanced risk measure will follow later in this paper. For now, it is important to recognize that:
Price volatility is a useful, albeit imperfect, proxy for risk.
Competition-driven shifts in supply and demand are primary drivers of volatility in asset prices.
8. Mitigating Inflation and Counterparty Risk
Mainstream financial theory often focuses on supply and demand risk—commonly measured by price volatility resulting from reduced scarcity (for example, when new competitors enter a market). However, this focus tends to overlook two critical risks: inflation risk and counterparty risk. Under a fiat money system, these risks become especially significant and interdependent.
Unlike scarcity and demand risks, which are relatively straightforward and well-researched, inflation and counterparty risks are tightly intertwined when governments control their currency. This interdependence renders the spendable M2 money supply far less predictable than it would be under a gold-backed system, where the money supply is externally constrained. Consequently, fiat money can become a poor unit of account, given the strategic uncertainty surrounding future M2 growth driven by unfunded government spending. This situation illustrates why fiat price volatility is no longer a reliable measure of true investment risk.
Fiat systems grant governments unilateral power to manipulate the money supply (M2), often prioritizing short-term political goals over long-term stability. According to A Walrasian Theory of Money and Barter (1994) from Harvard Business School, politicians—acting as rational agents—tend to favor money creation over unpopular fiscal measures such as tax hikes. This “path of least resistance” perpetuates inflationary cycles.
Unlike gold-backed systems, where scarcity is externally enforced, fiat money’s value hinges on trust in policymakers. When governments monetize debt through unfunded spending, they dilute the currency’s purchasing power, effectively reducing the scarcity—and therefore the value—of each monetary unit. In this sense, inflation risk becomes a form of artificial scarcity manipulation. Similarly, counterparty risk arises because the same entity that controls scarcity—the state—can alter the rules of the game at will, impacting both the accessibility and reliability of your investments.
Before we run, however, we must first learn how to walk. Let us begin by examining counterparty risk in investing—particularly as it relates to active trading, where counterparty risk arises from trading against a better-informed counterpart. Given this, passive investing remains the only sensible strategy for retail investors, who are, by definition, less well informed and less resourced than institutional players. This conclusion aligns with mainstream financial theory, as articulated by figures such as John Bogle, Eugene Fama, and William Sharpe, and is borne out by practice. Even active investors like Warren Buffett often recommend passive strategies for those lacking the time or expertise to replicate the approach of large institutional players like Berkshire Hathaway.
The Arithmetic of Active Management
For rational retail investors who wish to preserve their purchasing power without dedicating their entire lives to investment expertise—those who value simplicity and prefer to enjoy life rather than continuously managing portfolios—active investing is not a viable option. This assertion is not mere opinion but an immutable fact, as self-evident as the Earth’s roughly spherical shape or the arithmetic truth that 2 + 2 = 4 (assuming a sufficient number of countable objects).
The certainty that active investing, on average, leads to lower returns for retail investors follows from a fundamental accounting identity—a mathematical truth as unassailable as any basic principle of mathematics. William F. Sharpe’s seminal 1991 paper, The Arithmetic of Active Management, is essential reading for any retail investor. In this work, the Nobel Prize–winning economist (and creator of the Capital Asset Pricing Model, or CAPM) demonstrates that, by definition, all investors collectively hold the market portfolio (M). Consequently, the following holds:
Passive Investors:
By holding the market portfolio (M), passive investors achieve returns equal to M minus minimal fees—often only a few basis points per year when using standard index funds.Active Investors:
By deviating from M, active investors as a group must underperform M by the sum of their costs—transaction fees, research expenses, taxes, and other trading frictions.
This result is not a hypothesis but a straightforward accounting identity—an arithmetic fact that is independently verifiable and permanently true. It guarantees that in any real-world market, after accounting for all costs, active investing is, on average, a negative-sum game for the typical retail investor.
Maintaining consistency with mainstream mathematical economics, this reasoning rests on the principle that any attempt by active managers to outperform the market necessitates that one investor’s gain is offset by another’s loss after costs are deducted. In efficient markets—where information is widely available and competition is intense—the net effect of these trading costs is that active management fails to deliver superior returns relative to a low-cost, passive approach. This conclusion is supported by empirical research and remains a cornerstone of modern portfolio theory.
The Systemic Disadvantage for Retail Investors: Being the Least Well Informed
Retail investors face a profound systemic disadvantage: they are the least informed participants in financial markets. Institutional players—armed with superior data, advanced predictive models, and faster execution capabilities—consistently outmaneuver individual traders. In unfettered markets, this information asymmetry creates a game-theoretic reality where the better-informed participant always prevails (Fama, 1970; Grossman & Stiglitz, 1980).
The Zero-Sum Reality of Active Trading
Active trading is not merely a negative-sum game after accounting for fees and taxes; it is fundamentally zero-sum before costs. For one trader to outperform the market by even a penny, another must underperform by that same amount. This arithmetic truth arises because all active traders collectively hold the same market portfolio (M). Retail investors, however, are not competing against peers but against institutions like Citadel, which profit from retail order flow—often labeled as “dumb flow”—to exploit predictable behavior (Barber & Odean, 2000). The odds of a retail trader profiting in this environment are akin to a novice defeating a Grandmaster in chess: possible in theory, but practically negligible.
Real-World Evidence Against Active Trading
The Rise of Passive Investing:
Over 50% of invested capital now flows into passive index funds, a trend pioneered by John Bogle’s Vanguard. This widespread shift reflects the consensus that active strategies, burdened by higher costs and adverse selection, fail to justify their expense (Bogle, 2007).Chronic Underperformance of Active Funds:
Decades of data reveal that mutual and hedge funds—both as a group and individually—rarely outperform the market after fees. Even funds with short-term success tend to revert to the mean, underscoring the inherent difficulty of sustaining active management gains (Sharpe, 1991; Malkiel, 2003).Exploitation by Sophisticated Counterparties:
Hedge funds profit systematically from retail trading, leveraging payment for order flow (PFOF) to front-run orders. Platforms like Robinhood, which advertise “free” trades, monetize this asymmetry, ensuring that retail investors face adversaries with far superior resources and information (Johnson, 2018).
The Bottom Line
Passive investing is the only rational strategy for retail investors. Active trading embeds unavoidable counterparty risk because the opposing side of every trade is almost certainly better informed. Even Warren Buffett, a legendary active investor, advises most individuals to simply “own the market.” Berkshire Hathaway’s success is built on scale, access, and expertise that retail investors cannot replicate.
Conclusion
Both theory and empirical evidence converge on one conclusion: active trading guarantees systemic losses for retail participants. As Bogle, Sharpe, and Buffett have consistently emphasized, diversification through low-cost index funds remains the sole viable path to wealth preservation and growth. In a market rigged by information asymmetry, passive investing isn’t just prudent—it’s essential for survival.
Supporting References:
Barber, B. M., & Odean, T. (2000). Trading is Hazardous to Your Wealth: The Common Stock Investment Performance of Individual Investors. Journal of Finance.
Bogle, J. C. (2007). Common Sense on Mutual Funds: New Imperatives for the Intelligent Investor. Wiley.
Fama, E. F. (1970). Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work. Journal of Finance.
Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets. American Economic Review.
Johnson, K. (2018). The Costs and Consequences of Payment for Order Flow. Financial Analysts Journal.
Malkiel, B. G. (2003). The Efficient Market Hypothesis and Its Critics. Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Sharpe, W. F. (1991). The Arithmetic of Active Management. Financial Analysts Journal.
9. Volatility Dually Defined: Diversifiable vs. Non-Diversifiable Risk
In finance, price volatility is commonly viewed as a key measure of an investment’s risk. According to mainstream theory, the greater the volatility (denominated in U.S. dollars), the riskier the asset is deemed. However, both in theory and in practice, investors are compensated only for non-diversifiable (systematic) risk—as measured by volatility. This principle underpins widely used models such as the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), the Fama–French 3–5 factor models, and multi-factor Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) frameworks (e.g., those developed by Barra, which incorporate numerous risk factors).
Before proceeding, let us define diversifiable and non-diversifiable risk more precisely:
Diversifiable Risk
Definition: Risks specific to an individual asset or sector that can be mitigated or eliminated through portfolio diversification.
Compensation: Investors are not rewarded for bearing diversifiable risk because it can be eliminated.Non-Diversifiable Risk
Definition: Systematic risks that affect the entire market or asset class and cannot be diversified away.
Compensation: These risks form the basis for investor compensation in models such as CAPM and related frameworks.
Although taking on diversifiable risk might seem profitable in theory, significant barriers prevent retail investors from exploiting it. For instance, operating a casino or lottery is essentially a means of monetizing diversifiable risk—but these activities are heavily regulated (typically reserved for state authorities or politically privileged entities), effectively excluding most retail investors. Attempting to run a private lottery or casino would likely invite severe legal consequences. Even card counting in blackjack—an effort to monetize diversifiable risk by exploiting the dealer’s prescribed strategy and changing odds (using Bayes’ rule as cards are removed)—is actively countered by casinos. In short, retail investors are systematically barred from profiting from diversifiable risk.
Institutional investors, however—such as those at RBC (where I previously managed a mathematical arbitrage portfolio)—can and do capitalize on diversifiable risk. This approach lies at the heart of hedge fund activities (e.g., Renaissance Technologies), which often generate near-riskless returns by exploiting pricing discrepancies. While I traded statistical arbitrage at RBC and later at a private hedge fund, the Sharpe ratios for these strategies ranged between 6 and 12, compared to approximately 1 for the S&P 500. Yet these methods remain inaccessible to retail investors, who generally lack the regulatory permissions, scale, specialized knowledge, and experience required to implement them effectively.
Volatility Is Only an Accurate Risk Measure in a Fully Unfettered Market
The relationship between price volatility and risk holds true only under the First Welfare Theorem’s assumptions—namely, perfectly competitive markets with unfettered exchange, rational actors, complete information, and a stable unit of account. In such a frictionless environment (akin to the Arrow–Debreu model), volatility serves as a reliable proxy for risk: unpredictable price movements signal uncertainty about future purchasing power. For example, gold has historically acted as a “minimum-variance ruler” due to its supply constraints and neutrality in pricing. When prices are measured in gold—providing a stable monetary base as defined by the U = S + E framework (where U represents the spendable money supply)—volatility accurately reflects true risk.
Breakdown in Fiat-Currency Regimes
However, the volatility–risk linkage fractures in fiat-currency systems, where legal tender laws and taxation enforce currency usage, thereby violating the “unfettered exchange” assumption. While Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) may oversimplify inflation dynamics (e.g., claiming that indefinite M2 expansion is non-inflationary), it correctly identifies that fiat systems rely on government coercion rather than on voluntary adoption. MMT’s limited validity in liquidity traps—where idle bank reserves suppress inflation—does not negate the broader axiom: ΔU=ΔS+ΔE
Here, U (the spendable money supply, as proxied by M2) drives E (nominal spending). Sustained increases in U inevitably raise E, fueling inflation in the absence of offsetting productivity gains.
Institutional Friction and Systemic Distortions
Regardless of debates over the inflationary effects of M2 expansion, one core insight is often overlooked: “fiat” means “by government decree.” This characteristic inherently violates the voluntary exchange assumption central to the Arrow–Debreu framework. In practice, governments—whether democratic or authoritarian—mandate fiat currency usage, creating institutional friction. Absent such coercion, societies tend to gravitate toward alternative monies, as evidenced by dollarization trends in some developing countries or the adoption of Bitcoin, whose supply is stable. These alternatives contrast sharply with fiat systems backed by rent-seeking institutions and entrenched banking monopolies.
The result is a systemic distortion—akin to friction in physics—that severs the direct link between volatility and risk, which would otherwise hold in frictionless markets (paralleling Newtonian motion in a vacuum). In fiat-dominated systems, this imposed friction not only undermines free trade and distorts price signals but also amplifies counterparty risk, particularly the unhedgeable risk stemming from governments’ discretionary mismanagement of the M2 money supply.
Historical and Constitutional Context
The U.S. Constitution’s Article I, Section 10, Clause 1 explicitly prohibits states from designating anything other than gold and silver coins as legal tender for debts. This early recognition reflects an understanding that precious metals require no legal mandate to function as money, whereas fiat currencies depend entirely on coercion. By mandating fiat, governments undermine the foundational premises of the First Welfare Theorem and the Arrow–Debreu model, rendering volatility an imperfect proxy for risk.
As explained in A Walrasian Theory of Money and Barter referenced above, politicians—acting as rational agents—tend to favor money creation over unpopular fiscal measures such as tax hikes. This “path of least resistance” perpetuates inflationary cycles, further destabilizing the unit of account and contributing to systemic distortions.
Key Takeaways
Idealized Markets: Volatility reliably signals risk only under Arrow–Debreu conditions—characterized by unfettered trade and a stable monetary base (e.g., when prices are measured in gold under a stable U = S + E framework).
Fiat Distortions: Legal tender laws and government coercion introduce friction, decoupling volatility from the underlying fundamentals of risk.
Systemic Implications: This friction amplifies counterparty risk, as the same entity controlling the money supply can alter the “rules of the game” at will.
Empirical Reality: Societies naturally seek stable alternatives (such as gold or Bitcoin) when freed from coercion, underscoring the fragility of fiat systems.
Historical Insight: The constitutional mandate limiting legal tender to gold and silver reflects early recognition of these distortions, highlighting the contrast between voluntary exchange in idealized markets and the imposed nature of fiat currency.
Volatility ≠ True Risk: Gold as a Long-Term Store of Value
While fiat systems may distort the relationship between volatility and risk, the difference becomes starkly evident when comparing long-term price stability using two different monetary units: fiat U.S. dollars versus gold. Over extended periods, the prices of goods and services (for example, a high-quality men’s suit) have remained remarkably stable when denominated in gold. Historical data—from the Roman Empire and the Middle Ages (pre-Renaissance), through 1920 (prior to the 1933 U.S. gold confiscation), and from 1975 (when private gold ownership resumed) to the present—demonstrate gold’s consistent ability to preserve purchasing power. In fact, the cost of a quality men’s suit has hovered around one troy ounce of gold for over 2,000 years, reflecting gold’s low long-term price volatility driven by its predictable supply growth and inherent scarcity.
In contrast, prices measured in fiat currencies—such as the U.S. dollar, whose spendable supply (M2) can expand unpredictably—exhibit significant long-term volatility. This volatility primarily stems from systematic inflation, which steadily erodes fiat’s purchasing power. Although fiat currencies often report modest annual CPI inflation rates (typically 1–2%), sustained inflation over the long term gradually diminishes the value of the unit of account.
Gold vs. Fiat in Practice
Gold as a Store of Value:
Gold preserves purchasing power over centuries, whereas fiat currencies gradually lose value due to persistent inflation.Gold’s Price Volatility:
Despite its long-term stability, gold’s short-term price can fluctuate by 10–15% annually when measured in US dollars. Paradoxically, consumer prices denominated in gold appear roughly ten times more volatile than those in fiat dollars. This is largely a statistical artifact: fiat inflation masks its own volatility by eroding the unit of account, while gold’s stable and predictable supply renders its short-term price swings more visible.Why Does Gold Appear More Volatile in the Short Term?
This divergence arises because alternative units of account (such as gold, silver, or Bitcoin) are priced in fiat currency. Governments require that taxes and official debts be paid in fiat, which anchors near-term demand and reinforces fiat’s role as the unit of account for quoting wages, consumer prices, and everyday transactions. Two outcomes emerge:
Stable Short-Term Price Indices:
Because government policies mandate the use of fiat for taxation and debt payments, official indices like the Consumer Price Index (CPI) tend to show relatively low short-term volatility. This stability is largely a result of fiat inflation being masked by the steady, institutionalized use of fiat in daily transactions.Amplified Volatility for Alternative Units:
In contrast, when prices are quoted in alternative units such as gold, even minor shifts in market sentiment, interest rates, or monetary policy are reflected as relatively large percentage changes. Gold’s inherent supply constraints and predictable growth make its short-term price swings more visible when measured against the fiat baseline.
These dynamics explain why, despite its long-term stability as a store of value, gold appears more volatile over short periods when compared to fiat currencies.
Fiat vs. Gold: Long-Term Value Preservation
While fiat currencies may appear less volatile in the short run due to their government-enforced status, they systematically lose value over time. In contrast, real-asset–backed currencies like gold exhibit far lower volatility in purchasing power over extended periods—thanks to their stable supply relative to the quantity of goods and services exchanged, and the absence of distortions caused by fractional reserve banking. Even if gold appears more volatile in the short term (when measured in fiat terms), its historical performance demonstrates that it maintains value far more effectively over the long run.
Key Insight: Volatility and Risk in Fiat-Dominated Markets
This nuanced relationship—illustrated by comparing gold and fiat—demonstrates that price volatility alone is not an accurate measure of risk in markets characterized by involuntary exchange mechanisms. Investors must distinguish between short-term volatility and long-term value preservation to assess risk accurately and make informed financial decisions.
Given that this is a cryptocurrency white paper, the following sections will explain precisely where Bitcoin fits into this framework.
10. Money-as-Object Dually Defined: Bearer vs. Permissioned
As Milton Friedman and other economists have observed, history demonstrates a well-established empirical fact: a vast array of real-world objects—both tangible and intangible—have functioned as money. Across cultures and eras, diverse items have served as media of exchange, stores of value, or units of account. Below is a categorized list of historically and culturally significant forms of money.
I. Historical and Cultural Forms of Money
Animal-Based Money
Cattle: One of the oldest forms of money. The Latin pecus (from which “pecuniary” is derived) refers to livestock, which was used as currency in ancient Africa, India, and Europe.
Sheep/Goats: Common in pastoral societies, as seen in ancient Mesopotamia and Mongolia.
Saltwater Shellfish: Cowrie shells functioned as a global currency for millennia in Africa, Asia, and Oceania.
Whale Teeth (Tabua): Used ceremonially as money in Fiji.
Animal Pelts: Examples include beaver pelts in colonial North America and squirrel pelts in medieval Russia.
Feather Money: Red-feather coils in Santa Cruz (Solomon Islands).
Agricultural & Food Commodities
Grains: Barley (the basis for the shekel) in ancient Mesopotamia; rice in feudal Japan.
Salt: Roman soldiers were paid in salarium (the origin of “salary”); salt was also used as currency in the Sahara trade and medieval Europe.
Cocoa Beans: Utilized by Aztec and Mayan societies both as currency and for luxury beverages.
Tea Bricks: Compressed tea served as currency in Siberia, Tibet, and Central Asia.
Pepper: Dubbed “black gold” in medieval Europe and even used as collateral.
Tobacco: Functioned as currency in colonial America (e.g., Virginia).
Precious Metals & Metal Objects
Gold: A universal store of value, employed in coins, bullion, and jewelry.
Silver: Widely minted into coins (e.g., the Greek drachma, Spanish dollar).
Copper: Used for smaller denominations (e.g., Roman as, Chinese cash coins).
Bronze/Steel: Manillas—bracelet-shaped metal rings—in West Africa.
Iron: Utilized for objects such as spits in ancient Greece and iron bars in pre-colonial Africa.
Hacksilver: Broken silver items traded by weight during the Viking Age.
Stone & Mineral Money
Rai Stones: Giant limestone discs on Yap Island (Micronesia).
Jade: Valued in Mesoamerica (Olmec, Maya) and China.
Obsidian: Employed in pre-Columbian Mesoamerica for both tools and trade.
Lapis Lazuli: Traded in ancient Afghanistan and Mesopotamia.
Textiles & Clothing
Wampum: Beaded belts made of quahog shells used by Native American tribes and in colonial North America.
Silk: Used as currency in China (Tang Dynasty) and along the Silk Road.
Cotton Cloth: Examples include Guinea cloth in West Africa and kente in Ghana.
Kula Ring Shells: Items such as soulava (red shell necklaces) and mwali (white armbands) used in Melanesia.
Tools & Weapons as Money
Spade Money (Bu): Bronze spade-shaped coins in Zhou Dynasty China.
Knife Money (Dao): Early Chinese currency shaped like blades.
Axe Heads: Used as money in West Africa and in Bronze Age Europe.
Hoes: Iron hoes used in parts of Africa (e.g., the Congo).
Beads & Ornaments
Glass Beads: Traded in Africa (e.g., Venetian beads exchanged for slaves or gold).
Amber: Baltic amber, prominent in Viking trade networks.
Pearls: Extensively used in trade across the Persian Gulf and Indian Ocean.
Paper & Promissory Money
Jiaozi: Recognized as the first paper money in Song Dynasty China (11th century).
Banknotes: Fiat currency issued by governments (e.g., U.S. dollar, euro).
Playing Cards: Used as emergency money in 17th‑century French Canada.
Cryptocurrencies & Digital Money
Bitcoin: A decentralized digital currency (established 2009).
Mobile Money: For instance, cellphone airtime/minutes as currency in parts of Africa (e.g., M‑Pesa in Kenya).
Virtual Currencies: In-game tokens such as World of Warcraft gold or Fortnite V‑Bucks.
Unusual & Niche Money
Cigarettes: Served as currency in prison economies (e.g., post‑WWII Germany, modern U.S. prisons).
Alcohol: Examples include rum in colonial Australia and whiskey in 19th‑century Alaska.
Human Skulls: Such as rosary pea beads strung on skulls in Borneo.
Terra Cotta Tokens: Used in ancient Mesopotamia to record debts.
Potlatch Gifts: Competitive gift‑giving among Pacific Northwest tribes as a display of wealth.
Emergency & Hyperinflation Money
Notgeld: German emergency money issued during post‑World War I hyperinflation.
Chocolate Wrappers: Used as currency in post‑World War II Germany.
Stamps: Glued to paper as makeshift currency during crises.
Collectibles & Modern Alternatives
Pokémon Cards: Traded as high‑value collectibles.
Beanie Babies: A speculative “currency” phenomenon in the 1990s.
Art: High‑value paintings used as stores of wealth.
II. The Bearer vs. Registered (Permissioned) Distinction
There are many ways in which all these different types of money can be taxonomized, or classified. For example, economists commonly distinguish between commodity money (a gold coin) vs representative money (a ledger entry, a tally stick, or a bank-note like US dollars) redeemable for commodity moeney, and fiat money, which is representative money not redeemable for anything.
However, despite the myriad forms that money can take, all real-world financial assets (including money) ultimately fall into one of one of two categories:
Bearer Instruments
Definition: Instruments that confer ownership solely by physical possession. In bearer instruments, whoever physically holds the item is deemed its owner.
Example: Bearer bonds—as famously depicted in the 1988 film Die Hard, where fictional thieves target $640 million in bearer bonds.
Characteristics: Bearer bonds were typically issued in large denominations to facilitate the transfer of substantial sums, particularly in contexts where anonymity was valued. Over time, as technology evolved and the risks of loss or theft became more apparent, investors increasingly shunned these instruments. The U.S. government formally discontinued the issuance of bearer bonds in 1982 under the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982.
Registered (Permissioned) Instruments
Definition: Instruments in which ownership is recorded and linked to a specific individual or entity. Only the registered owner is entitled to manage or transfer the instrument.
Example: Standard bonds that require identity verification for transactions, or equities held in your brokerage account.
Characteristics: This permissioned structure improves transparency and accountability by enabling authorities or banks to track or freeze assets if necessary. Registered assets include equities, bonds, and index funds held in brokerage accounts at institutions like Fidelity, Schwab, or JPMorgan. These instruments require formal permission or verification to trade, which can help deter illicit activity.
The same distinction applies to money, both historically and today:
Bearer Money:
Examples: Cash (banknotes and coins) and physical precious metals (bars, coins).
Features: Ownership is determined solely by possession, allowing for a high degree of anonymity. However, this anonymity can also facilitate illicit activities—for example, bearer bonds, cash, and even Bitcoin have been used in ransom payments or drug trafficking.
Registered (Permissioned) Money:
Examples: Non‑cash bank accounts (e.g., checking accounts) and other financial instruments where transactions require identity verification (for instance, spending money from a brokerage account or writing a check, which requires your signature as the account owner).
Features: The permissioned nature makes it easier to track or freeze assets, serving as a deterrent against illegal transactions.
Bottom Line
Bearer money belongs to whoever physically holds it (or it’s wallet’s private key), providing significant anonymity but also a greater risk of misuse. In contrast, registered (permissioned) money is linked to a specific identity and requires formal verification for transfers. This fundamental distinction underpins both historical and modern monetary systems and has important implications for regulation, asset tracking, and the potential for misuse.
11. Bitcoin: The Safest Existing Bearer Money Object
For law-abiding individuals, money’s value is measured by its ability to serve as a store of value, a medium of exchange, and a unit of account. While critics often focus on the potential for illicit use of bearer money, such concerns are largely irrelevant for everyday users. In practice, most law-abiding individuals are far more troubled by the real-world drawback of permissioned money—such as bank deposits or digital fiat—which exposes them to counterparty risk: the necessity of obtaining third-party permission to access or spend their funds.
Bearer money—whether in the form of cash, gold, or Bitcoin—eliminates this counterparty risk by granting users direct, permissionless ownership of their funds; you can spend your Bitcoin whenever you want. Consequently, a growing number of lawyers and financial advisors now recommend allocating a portion of one’s wealth to liquid bearer assets, precisely because these assets cannot be unilaterally frozen or confiscated (e.g., via a Cyprus‑style bail-in).
From a law-abiding end-user’s perspective, bearer money exhibits exactly two disadvantages compared to non-bearer (permissioned) money:
Vulnerability to Theft:
Physical bearer instruments—such as cash—are inherently more susceptible to physical theft than registered bank accounts.Inability to Send Remotely:
Physical cash cannot be instantly transmitted across long distances merely by debiting and crediting ledgers, unlike bank-issued registered money, which is designed for efficient global transactions.
Recognizing that there are only two types of money—bearer (no permission required to spend, e.g., cash) and registered (requires identification to spend and receive payment, e.g., a bank deposit)—and understanding that bearer money has two inherent weaknesses (ease of theft and inability to send remotely), it becomes clear why Bitcoin has achieved such a huge market capitalization. Bitcoin directly addresses both major shortcomings of cash:
Remote Transfer:
Bitcoin can be spent from anywhere in the world and received globally, instantly and without relying on any central intermediary.Harder to Steal:
Stealing Bitcoin is more costly than stealing any other bearer instrument. Its robust digital security protocols and decentralized network ensure that theft requires overcoming enormous technical and economic hurdles.
As a result, Bitcoin eliminates the two key limitations of physical bearer instruments by retaining a permissionless digital format while providing the convenience of instant global transfer—central factors that contribute to its high market value. This is the short answer to why Bitcoin is so highly regarded.
For a historical perspective, imagine if Bitcoin had existed in the era depicted in The Golden Calf (Ilf and Petrov, 1931). Alexandr Koreiko could have moved his wealth across borders instantly—bypassing the novel’s arduous Polish border crossing by Ostap Bender, after which he famously vows to become a property manager. Modern parallels abound. In present-day Russia, for example, people routinely exchange suitcases of cash (in dollars, rubles, euros, etc.) at well-known offices in Moscow City for another form of bearer money—Bitcoin or USDT (Tether)—which they can later convert into registered bank-account money in financial hubs such as Dubai.
Bitcoin’s roughly $2 trillion valuation stems from its role as a form of bearer money that is demonstrably more secure against theft than any alternative. The immense expenditure on processing Bitcoin payments by miners—spending more on electricity than an entire country like Argentina—renders a 51% attack prohibitively expensive compared to other cryptocurrencies that spend less on mining. Consequently, Bitcoin’s robust security model underpins its status as the most valuable cryptocurrency, precisely because it is currently the most expensive bearer asset in the world to steal (as of February 11, 2025).
12. Assessing True Risk and Returns in Fiat-Priced Investments
Investing inherently involves sacrificing current purchasing power—reflected in money’s unit‑of‑account function—in exchange for greater purchasing power in the future. A rational investor seeks assets with predictable future cash flows so that the wealth forgone today yields higher real (inflation‑adjusted) value tomorrow. In essence, the goal of investing is to enhance future consumption rather than merely generating nominal gains.
Real vs. Nominal Returns
Rational investors focus on real returns rather than nominal figures. The key issue is not how much in dividends or interest is received in nominal terms but whether the future purchasing power of those cash flows exceeds the purchasing power sacrificed today.
Fiat-Denominated Investments and Systemic (Undiversifiable) Risk
Today, most assets—except for certain inflation‑hedged options like gold, silver, or select cryptocurrencies—generate cash flows in fiat currencies (e.g., U.S. dollars) because of legal tender and tax laws. Although fiat price volatility may not fully capture the erosion of purchasing power (especially compared to alternative monetary units like gold), systemic risk remains the best available metric for comparing the relative risks of fiat‑priced assets. Models such as the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) offer a first‑order approximation of how scarcity and demand factors operate in a fiat context, even if they do not fully account for fiat‑specific distortions like money printing or policy interventions.
How CAPM Frames Systemic Risk
CAPM posits that investors are compensated only for bearing non‑diversifiable (systemic) risk—the portion of market volatility that cannot be eliminated through diversification. Under typical fiat‑market conditions:
Lower‑Risk Cash Flows → Lower Yields:
Investments with stable, predictable income (e.g., high‑quality government bonds) offer lower yields, reflecting their low systemic risk.Riskier, Less Certain Cash Flows → Higher Yields:
Assets with more volatile and uncertain cash flows (e.g., high‑yield corporate debt or emerging‑market assets) must offer higher yields to attract capital.
Empirical Observations
Empirical data consistently show:
Predictable, Lower‑Risk Cash Flows Yield Lower Returns:
Example: High‑quality government bonds, considered “risk‑free” within their jurisdictions, command lower coupon rates.Riskier, Less Certain Cash Flows Yield Higher Returns:
Example: Companies with cyclical earnings or high leverage must offer higher bond yields or equity returns to attract investors.
Key outcomes include:
Higher Corporate Bond Yields:
Corporate bonds generally yield more than government bonds due to higher credit and default risks.S&P 500 Earnings Yield Correlation:
The earnings yield on the S&P 500 tends to track bond yields. When bond yields rise, equities typically exhibit higher earnings yields (i.e., lower price‑to‑earnings ratios) to remain competitive.
Why Retail Investors Struggle to Outperform
Once uncertainty is factored in, most investment alternatives yield similar risk‑adjusted outcomes on a systemic basis. Two main challenges explain why retail investors find it difficult to beat the market:
Efficient Markets:
Publicly available information is rapidly incorporated into asset prices, leaving little room for systematic out-performance without superior private knowledge or specialized strategies.Rational Compensation for Risk:
The market rewards only systemic risk while discounting diversifiable (idiosyncratic) risk. Retail traders typically lack the data, scale, and regulatory flexibility needed to exploit niche inefficiencies.
Consequently, even though CAPM has its limitations under fiat conditions, its risk‑return framework demonstrates that assets with predictable, lower‑risk cash flows yield lower returns, while riskier, less certain cash flows command higher yields. This framework further underscores that retail investors, being the least informed, cannot “beat the market” without unique insights, larger capital bases, or special regulatory permissions—privileges generally reserved for institutional players.
Gold as an Example of Public Information Being Priced In
Before 1974—when President Gerald Ford reinstated private gold ownership—U.S. dollars functioned essentially as fractional ownership certificates for gold, with the government fixing an official exchange rate. For instance, in the late 1960s, French President Charles de Gaulle’s insistence on converting dollars into gold at the official rate contributed to President Nixon’s 1971 decision to end gold convertibility. Consequently, the 1971 peg did not reflect a true market price.
By 1974–1975, after private gold ownership resumed, gold traded at about $160 per ounce—roughly 1/16 of its current level of approximately $2,600 per ounce. Over the next 50 years, the M2 money supply expanded from roughly $900 billion to $21 trillion—a 23‑fold increase—while gold’s price rose about 16‑fold, less than the implied 23‑fold rise. Newly mined gold increased total supply by roughly 1.3% per year, meaning the “spendable” gold supply expanded in tandem. Had the gold supply remained static, gold’s price might have soared even higher. Instead, today’s gold price aligns with market expectations of monetary inflation (both in gold and M2), suggesting that inflation—whether in fiat or gold supply—has been fully priced in, as economic theory predicts.
Summary: True‑Risk Market Facts vs. Conventional EMH
Comparing true risk—the risk of losing real purchasing power—with nominal volatility measured in fiat currency reveals why retail investors face daunting odds in fiat-dominated, information-asymmetric markets. Contrary to the conventional Efficient Market Hypothesis, core true‑risk market facts—grounded in mathematical economics and game theory—demonstrate that retail investors who attempt to outperform the market are fighting a losing battle.
Why Retail Investors Are the “Least Well‑Informed”
By definition, retail investors lack many advantages enjoyed by institutional participants:
Limited Access to Data and Expertise:
Retail investors typically do not have access to real‑time market feeds, proprietary research tools, or specialized training.Slower Execution:
Brokerages serving retail clients generally cannot match the speed and sophistication of high‑frequency or institutional trading platforms.Smaller Capital Base:
Retail portfolios usually lack the diversification potential or negotiating power that large institutional funds command.
In any market characterized by information asymmetry, better-informed participants profit at the expense of the less informed—much like an amateur facing a world‑champion chess player. Just as a world‑champion human chess player would have no chance against a computer like AlphaZero or Stockfish, which have been proven to outperform any human, retail investors are at a distinct disadvantage. This is why hedge funds actively buy retail order flow—leveraging superior data, faster execution, and advanced predictive models to profit from less‑informed trades.
Grounding the Principle in Economics
Several foundational economic theories reinforce these conclusions:
Akerlof’s “Market for Lemons” (1970, Nobel Prize 2001):
Demonstrates how information asymmetry leads to welfare losses for the less informed.Agency Theory (Jensen & Meckling):
Explains how misaligned incentives and uneven information flows allow better‑informed agents to exploit less‑informed principals.Public Choice Theory (1986 Nobel Prize):
Reveals how those with superior information and stronger incentives shape outcomes in their favor.
Gold as an Illustrative Example
The historical evolution of gold pricing illustrates how public information is fully incorporated into asset prices. The transition from a gold-backed U.S. dollar to a fiat currency in the early 1970s disrupted the official gold peg, leading to a gradual rise in gold prices that closely mirrors expectations of monetary inflation. This example underscores that, while retail investors cannot reliably beat market pricing based on true risk, public information—including monetary inflation—remains a key determinant of asset values.
Conclusion
Decades of economic research confirm that less‑informed participants incur welfare losses when competing against better‑informed market actors. For everyday investors, the lesson is clear: true risk is not solely about price volatility but also about recognizing—and avoiding—battles that are unwinnable in the face of systematic informational imbalances. This assessment of risk and return, grounded in both theoretical models like CAPM and empirical observations, explains why retail investors struggle to outperform and why the market compensates primarily for systemic risk.
14. What Are BWBs, and What Is Their True Risk?
Bearer Water Bonds (BWBs) are essentially bearer bonds—similar to those portrayed in the 1988 film Die Hard (in which fictional thieves attempt to steal $640 million in bearer bonds), except that BWBs are fully AML and KYC compliant. In our case, BWBs are structured and sold much like carbon credits or mineral rights in Texas. One BWB (or “bob”) entitles the holder to receive roughly 6,700 gallons of water from the source, delivered in an empty tanker. They take the form of legally binding private contracts where each token (or BWB) is redeemable for spring water at the source.
BWBs low risk stems from our ability to undergo a full audit by any reputable accounting firm, which verifies direct ownership of the mineral rights being fractionalized through our stablecoin under New Hampshire State property law.
(Note: The same property law underpins the ownership of assets in the S&P 500 Index; if you own a REIT, you do so under that same legal framework.)
In the context of BWBs, the “mineral right” being fractionalized is the right to extract a commodity—natural spring water—that the FDA currently classifies as suitable for human consumption. The water source is located at 10 Farr Road, Pittsburg, New Hampshire, where the property owner is licensed by the state to extract up to 360,000 gallons (250 gallons per minute) of spring water per day in perpetuity, subject to standard environmental and regulatory requirements.
Because the eventual “dividend payments” from BWBs will be realized in the form of a monetizable commodity—FDA‑approved spring water (a commodity often considered more valuable than gold in certain contexts)—these stablecoins currently function exactly as do commodity‑backed securities. To assess their true risk, we refer to the four key risk categories introduced earlier:
Counterparty Risk
Inflation Risk
Scarcity Risk
Demand (Lack of Demand) Risk
Below, we compare how bearer water bonds stack up against other so‑called “low‑risk” investments in terms of their real‑asset‑backed preservation of purchasing power—that is, their “true risk” as real‑world investable assets.
Why Bearer Water Bonds Are the Lowest True‑Risk Investment
Having identified the four fundamental risks underlying any investment—(1) counterparty, (2) inflation, (3) scarcity, and (4) demand—we now ask: Why might BWBs be safer than even TIPS (Treasury Inflation‑Protected Securities)?
TIPS are often hailed as near‑zero‑risk assets because they are backed by the full faith and credit of the U.S. government and are designed to protect against inflation. Yet, bearer water bonds—issued as private contracts under U.S. property law in New Hampshire—can outperform TIPS on two key dimensions: counterparty risk and inflation risk. This is because water bonds effectively neutralize scarcity and demand risk.
1. Lower Counterparty Risk via Property Rights
TIPS Depend on Government Solvency:
Although TIPS are adjusted for inflation, they ultimately rely on the U.S. Treasury’s ability and willingness to honor its obligations. While a federal default is historically unlikely, political disputes (e.g., over debt ceilings and government spending) introduce systemic uncertainty or tail risk.Bearer Water Bonds Depend on Enforceable Property Law:
By contrast, BWBs hinge on real property rights that have been established through centuries of American jurisprudence and are recorded on the blockchain. In Pittsburgh, NH—where these water rights are located—state property and environmental regulations provide robust legal protection for tangible, extractable resources such as water.Property Law Underpins Even the S&P 500:
The same legal framework that secures these water rights also underlies every physical asset owned by publicly traded companies. Even firms that appear “stable” on paper depend on foundational property laws for their operations.
2. Built‑In Inflation Protection Beyond Government Decrees
TIPS Adjust for Official CPI:
TIPS principal and interest payments track the Consumer Price Index (CPI). However, official inflation metrics can diverge from real‑world cost increases due to changes in CPI methodology or political and economic factors that influence inflation measurement.Bearer Water Bonds Are Commodity‑Backed:
Unlike TIPS, whose value depends on government‑calculated inflation, BWBs pay “dividends” in the form of actual spring water—an inelastic, physical commodity essential for human consumption, agriculture, and industry. As water resources become scarcer and more regulated, the real purchasing power of fresh, clean water is likely to hold steady or even increase over time, independent of government inflation metrics.
3. Scarcity and Demand Bolster Long‑Term Viability
Scarcity Dynamics:
TIPS rely on continued government issuance and market appetite for Treasuries. In contrast, BWBs are anchored by an essential natural resource with a finite supply. Climate variability and population growth further drive up the value of clean water over time.Demand Stability:
Demand for water remains robust—even in weaker economic conditions—because clean water is a necessity rather than a luxury. This stability sharply contrasts with many other commodities and financial instruments that are more vulnerable to shifting consumer trends.
Conclusion: A Path to True‑Risk Minimization
From a true‑risk perspective—where the objective is to preserve or grow real purchasing power while minimizing counterparty exposure—bearer water bonds offer a uniquely secure option:
Counterparty Risk:
Anchored by enforceable property law rather than governmental solvency—and by virtue of being a bearer instrument—BWBs provide dual protection against counterparty risk.Inflation Risk:
Supported by the tangible value of an essential commodity, BWBs are less vulnerable to distortions arising from volatile government inflation metrics.Scarcity Risk:
BWBs are grounded in the inherent scarcity of water—a stark contrast to the unlimited expansion of fiat money.Demand Risk:
Driven by near‑universal human and industrial needs, the market for potable water remains robust and resilient.
While TIPS can certainly complement traditional portfolios, BWBs arguably offer an even higher level of safety and inflation protection. They are backed by real assets, safeguarded by property rights, and buoyed by inelastic demand—all while functioning as a bearer instrument that minimizes counterparty risk and precludes theft and criminal misuse through stringent credit approval processes. For investors seeking to minimize true risk, BWBs can provide an unparalleled level of security, transcending many of the vulnerabilities inherent in fiat‑based investments.
15. Final Conclusion: Lessons from Real-World Water Rights and the Future of Bearer Water Bonds (BWBs)
Throughout this paper, we have demonstrated how bearer water bonds (BWBs) provide a uniquely low‑risk solution—grounded in tangible property law, backed by an essential, inelastic commodity, and recorded on a trustless blockchain. By examining the four fundamental risks (counterparty, inflation, scarcity, and demand), we have shown how these privately structured, commodity‑backed securities can outperform even Treasury Inflation‑Protected Securities (TIPS) for investors seeking to minimize true risk.
A Proven Track Record of Profiting from Water
We are not the first to recognize water’s value as a strategic asset. High‑profile figures such as T. Boone Pickens in Texas and the Resnicks in California have demonstrated that proactively acquiring water rights can be immensely profitable—especially in regions where scarcity drives premium valuations. Other farmland owners, investment funds, and “water‑rights billionaires” have similarly capitalized on securing access to water sources. Their success highlights several core insights:
Real Assets in an Era of Scarcity:
As populations grow and climate pressures intensify, reliable access to fresh water becomes increasingly valuable. Investors who secure ownership or control of finite water resources early may benefit disproportionately from rising scarcity premiums.Strategic Advantage Through Regulation and Rights:
By navigating complex water laws—whether in California’s intricate system of water districts or Texas’s “rule of capture”—savvy individuals and entities leverage legal expertise to obtain preferential water allocations, turning a critical natural resource into a profitable venture.Challenges and Controversies:
Large‑scale water‑rights acquisitions can draw public scrutiny and calls for tighter regulation, particularly when communities perceive the “privatization” of a fundamental human need. Nonetheless, for those equipped with legal expertise, capital, and a long‑term perspective, the financial rewards often outweigh these risks.
Water Bonds: The Next Evolution in Water Investment
Water bonds mark a natural evolution of this broader trend. Rather than individual billionaires discreetly acquiring water rights, these private contracts enable qualified investors to participate in fractional ownership of revenue‑generating water sources. Where T. Boone Pickens and others had to secure pipeline approvals or oversee agricultural operations, water bonds simplify the process—allowing participants to invest in commodity‑backed water rights without the complexities of large‑scale infrastructure projects.
Crucially, water bonds also adopt passive investing principles. Instead of attempting to outperform volatile markets, bondholders rely on water’s inherent scarcity and inelastic demand—along with robust property‑law protections—to preserve and grow real purchasing power over time.
Recording and Maintaining Fractional Ownership on the Blockchain
In addition to underlying property rights and water’s intrinsic value, bearer water bonds benefit from a secure, trustless system for tracking fractional ownership. BWBs are blockchain-based tokens redeemable for a 30 minute time slot at the pump, sufficient to fill a standard 6,700 gallon stainless steel container used to transport FDA certified food products such as milk. BWBs are Ethereum‑based smart contracts—later migrating to the TNT (Transparent Network Technology) blockchain. By digitizing the ownership registry, this approach minimizes counterparty risk within the investor pool, where another fractional owner or intermediary might otherwise threaten one’s claim.
Key Advantages of Blockchain‑Based Ownership
Transparency:
Every fractional share transfer is publicly verifiable, eliminating hidden or unauthorized transactions.Security:
The ledger’s immutability ensures that past records cannot be altered, reducing the risk of fraudulent share reassignments.Decentralized Validation:
A distributed network confirms ownership transfers, removing reliance on a single “trusted” third‑party bookkeeper.Regulatory Compatibility:
When combined with KYC/AML or other compliance frameworks, blockchain‑based records provide a robust audit trail that aligns with legal requirements for private securities issuance.
By integrating blockchain technology—particularly the upcoming TNT trustless and permissioned network—water bonds reinforce the real‑asset foundation underpinning their value. This approach extends the principles of tangible, inelastic demand and transparent legal rights into the digital realm, further mitigating counterparty risk while enhancing long‑term resilience.
Looking Ahead: TNT and the Future of Bearer Water Bonds
While many existing blockchains face limitations, the TNT blockchain—detailed in its own white paper—aims to overcome these challenges with a transparent, trustless, and permissioned design. By adopting TNT, bearer water‑bond issuers can ensure that fractional ownership certificates remain tamper‑proof and easily verifiable, thereby strengthening both security and scalability.
Bearer water bonds embody a powerful convergence of vital resource ownership, robust legal protections, and cutting‑edge blockchain technology. By pairing the stability of tangible assets with the transparency of digital systems, these bonds offer a compelling alternative investment vehicle—providing superior protection against four key risks: counterparty, inflation, scarcity, and demand. As global demand for clean water intensifies, BWBs are poised to become a transformative force in low‑risk, asset‑backed investing.
A Timeless Principle: Direct Ownership
For those recalling the film Die Hard, consider Hans Gruber’s pursuit of physical bearer bonds: whoever holds those certificates owns them outright—no identity verification required. BWBs operate similarly but in digital form. If you hold the token (i.e., the private key), you own the underlying water asset with no counterparty risk. This reiterates a timeless principle:
If you hold it, you own it. No intermediaries—just direct ownership.
This hallmark of a bearer instrument is defined by three characteristics:
No Centralized Registry:
Ownership is not tied to any official ledger or individual’s name.No Additional Documentation:
Possession alone serves as proof of ownership.Freedom of Transfer:
Bonds can be physically exchanged or digitally transferred without third‑party involvement.
Although modern regulatory frameworks require KYC (Know Your Customer) steps during issuance or redemption, the technical foundation remains unchanged. Much like in Die Hard, holding the token equates to ownership—mirroring traditional bearer bonds and illustrating how BWBs function as true blockchain‑based bearer instruments. Nobody can confiscate your BWB coins. We are responsible citizens who fully abide by AML and KYC laws, meaning that while BWB coins can be frozen temporarily (since no honest wallet will accept a credit from a proven criminal), without your private key, nobody—even God—can exchange your token for water.
This is what makes TNT’s trustless system revolutionary: it eliminates reliance on untrusted intermediaries. The only person who can redeem your token is you, ensuring with absolute certainty that ownership is secure and independently verifiable—an approach comprehensively detailed in the [TNT white paper].
Legal Q&A: Bearer Water Bonds (BWBs) & Compliance Risks
1. What happens if regulators determine that BWBs require registration?
Absolutely nothing changes—we simply register them as required. We have multiple compliance options, including:
Regulation A+ (Reg A+): for a limited public offering.
Regulation S (Reg S): for international investors.
Full SEC Registration (S-1 Bond Offering): if public trading is pursued.
CFTC Commodity Exemption: we are currently pursuing a no-action letter for this, as we believe that BWBs qualify as a physical commodity contract rather than a financial instrument.
The key point is that compliance is always the priority. Section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 broadly prohibits manipulative or deceptive practices in securities transactions. However, we believe that refraining from making misleading statements and from presenting forward‑looking hypotheses as facts is prudent practice—regardless of what we’re selling, including BWBs. Under this statute, the SEC created Rule 10b‑5, which explicitly bans fraud, false statements, and material omissions in securities trading. Together, these regulations empower both regulators and private parties to combat market fraud and uphold fair market practices.
Regarding Water‑Backed Tokens (WBTs), even though we believe they do not qualify as securities under the Howey Test, we treat them as securities in all communications to ensure full compliance with Section 10(b) and Rule 10b‑5 principles. This means:
✅ All claims are independently verifiable.
✅ No misleading statements are made.
✅ Forward‑looking statements are clearly labeled as projections.
✅ Investors are encouraged to independently verify all information.
By adhering to these strict compliance standards, we mitigate legal risks, maintain investor trust, and ensure transparency—regardless of WBTs’ final regulatory classification.
2. What if regulators demand more AML/KYC enforcement on BWBs?
Unlike early blockchain systems—which were designed without built-in compliance mechanisms—BWBs are structured from the ground up to meet and exceed modern AML/KYC standards. Our system ensures that both parties in a transaction must validate the transfer, providing a level of compliance equal to or greater than traditional financial systems.
How We Ensure AML/KYC Compliance:
Dual-Approval Transaction Model:
Unlike Bitcoin’s unilateral transaction system, BWBs require two signatures for any transfer to be valid:The sending wallet must sign the debit.
The receiving wallet must sign the credit.
If either party fails to sign, the transaction does not occur.
Custodian-Based Transaction Approval:
We can assign all credit approvals to a regulated custodian (e.g., JPMorgan or another commercial bank), which can block any transaction that does not meet AML/KYC standards.Equivalent or Superior Compliance to U.S. M2 Bank Accounts:
Since all transactions require explicit custodian approval, BWBs can be as compliant as any existing fiat bank account. Just as no U.S. bank will accept a large cash deposit without proper verification, no BWB transaction can occur unless it meets regulatory standards.
Why This Makes BWBs Fully AML/KYC Compliant:
✔ No Anonymous Transfers:
BWBs cannot be transferred anonymously—unlike certain cryptocurrencies, each transaction requires recipient verification.
✔ Full Commercial Banking Oversight:
Just as U.S. banks monitor large transactions, BWBs can be monitored and controlled by a regulated custodian.
✔ Transparent Auditability:
Since all transactions pass through AML/KYC-compliant institutions, regulators have a clear and transparent record of ownership and transfers.
Bottom Line:
BWBs are fully adaptable to any required AML/KYC enforcement level. By integrating custodian-controlled approvals and dual-signature validation, BWBs achieve a level of compliance that exceeds that of cash transactions or traditional cryptocurrencies. If regulators require even stricter controls, we can implement additional oversight and reporting mechanisms to align with evolving legal standards.
3. How do you ensure that BWBs can always be redeemed for water, and what happens if delivery becomes impractical?
BWBs function similarly to carbon credits, where ownership conveys a real-world usage right rather than a financial return. When BWBs are sold, the seller grants an easement that secures the right for fractional shareholders to access and extract water.
Legal & Operational Structure:
Easement Agreement Guarantees Access
Just as carbon credit agreements require timberland owners to maintain a certain CO₂ sequestration level, BWBs contractually guarantee that water will remain accessible to token holders.Dedicated Infrastructure for Redemption
Shareholders can access the well and an authorized facility to exchange empty containers for full ones—a standard industry practice for spring water distribution. In this system, token holders redeem BWBs by swapping an empty container for a full one.Limited Liability for Acts of God
Just as carbon credit issuers are not liable for natural disasters (e.g., forest fires destroying carbon-sequestering trees), we cannot be held liable for force majeure events that may impact water availability (e.g., droughts, regulatory changes, environmental disasters).Obligation to Maintain Pump & Prevent Contamination
Our primary responsibility under the easement is twofold:To prevent third parties from contaminating the water source to the best of our ability.
To ensure that the pump remains operational and can fill empty containers with water.
This is a clear but limited, enforceable contractual obligation—meaning we are responsible only within our reasonable control.
Shared Maintenance Costs
Shareholders collectively cover maintenance costs, similar to how Ethereum users pay gas fees for transactions. These costs may be:Collected at the point of water redemption (e.g., when picking up water at the source),
Assessed periodically across all shareholders, or
Implemented through a combination of both methods to ensure sustainability.
What Happens If Delivery Becomes Impractical?
If unforeseen circumstances prevent the physical redemption of BWBs (e.g., due to regulatory shifts, environmental factors, or well depletion), the issued tokens will lose their redeemability—just as mineral rights become worthless if extraction is no longer feasible (e.g., when gold, lithium, oil, or gas deposits are exhausted).
To be absolutely clear:
BWBs do not provide a guarantee of water extraction under all conditions—we are not God.
We are fractionalizing mineral rights and the infrastructure for their extraction—nothing more.
If a drought or regulatory action prevents extraction, the value of BWBs will reflect those conditions.
BWBs provide fractional mineral rights, which carry the same risks as any other property-based resource right. While we:
Ensure access to water and maintain the necessary infrastructure,
Work to protect environmental conditions, and
Are contractually obligated to operate the pump,
government actions, force majeure events, or other external factors could impact the ability to extract water—and in such cases, the tokens would lose their practical utility.
4. What legal protections do BWB holders have if the issuer fails to meet obligations?
Because BWBs are issued under a contract governed by New Hampshire state law, BWB holders have multiple layers of legal protection to enforce their rights if the issuer fails to meet its obligations.
Legal Recourse for BWB Holders
1. Right to Sue for Breach of Contract (Enforceable in Court)
If the well owner refuses to deliver water, BWB holders have a clear legal right to sue in New Hampshire state court under contract law. The court can:
Order specific performance: Compelling the well owner to deliver the water as promised.
Award financial damages: Compensating BWB holders for losses incurred due to non-delivery.
Issue an injunction: Preventing the well owner from selling water to others while ignoring BWB obligations.
2. Right to Place a Lien on the Property (Securing Your Claim)
If the issuer defaults, BWB holders can place a lien on the property that legally encumbers the well and its assets until the debt is satisfied.
This means the well cannot be sold, transferred, or refinanced without settling the BWB holders' claims.
If the issuer refuses to comply, a court can force the sale of the well to satisfy obligations to BWB holders.
3. Priority Legal Standing in Bankruptcy & Liquidation
If the issuer declares bankruptcy, BWB holders may have a secured claim on the well and its associated assets.
Since BWBs are linked to a tangible property right (water extraction easement), holders may have priority standing over unsecured creditors.
BWB holders can petition the court to either compel continued water delivery or liquidate the well assets to compensate investors.
4. Easement-Based Legal Protections (Direct Property Access Rights)
Because BWB holders own an easement-backed right to water extraction, their claims are not merely financial—they are tied to real property rights, making them stronger than traditional unsecured contracts.
Even if the well owner defaults, BWB holders retain an independent legal right to access and extract water.
If the well is ever sold, the easement survives the sale, meaning the new owner is still legally bound to honor the water access rights of BWB holders.
How This Compares to Other Legal Protections
Stronger than a basic contract claim:
Because BWBs are tied to real property (the well and water rights), they provide higher enforcement power than unsecured contracts.More enforceable than typical investment securities:
Unlike stocks or corporate bonds, which depend on corporate solvency, BWB holders have direct legal claims on physical assets (water and infrastructure).Comparable to oil, gas, or mineral rights ownership:
Like mineral rights in Texas, BWBs grant enforceable extraction rights that survive ownership transfers and legal disputes.
Bottom Line
BWB holders have strong legal protections under contract and property law, ensuring their rights are enforceable in multiple ways:
✔ Lawsuits for breach of contract
✔ Court-ordered water delivery or financial damages
✔ Liens on the well property to secure claims
✔ Priority legal standing in bankruptcy or liquidation
✔ Easement rights that survive ownership transfers
In other words, BWB ownership is backed by the full weight of U.S. property law, making it a highly secure fractional resource right—on par with legally recognized mineral rights, land easements, and water access agreements.
5. Can BWBs be resold or transferred, and if so, how is ownership enforced?
Yes, BWBs can be resold or transferred, subject to regulatory compliance and system-enforced restrictions to ensure legal validity and security.
How BWBs Function as a Transferable Asset
1. Stablecoin Structure
BWBs are blockchain-based tokens issued by the property owner in a fixed quantity and are redeemable for one tank of water per token.
2. Representative Money Model
Similar to gold-backed U.S. dollars in 1923—when paper notes were redeemable for gold at banks—BWBs function as redeemable stablecoins backed by real water rights. However, unlike paper money, BWBs are directly tied to an enforceable legal property right (the well), ensuring their redeemability.
How Ownership Is Enforced
1. Blockchain-Based Enforcement
Similar to Bitcoin and other digital assets, BWB ownership is secured on the blockchain, making transactions publicly verifiable and tamper-proof.
2. Regulatory Restrictions on Transfers
While BWBs can be freely transferred between compliant wallets, our system automatically blocks transactions involving restricted wallets, ensuring full AML/KYC compliance.
3. Custodian & Compliance Controls
Similar to restricted stock held by corporate insiders, BWBs can be structured to require custodian approval for specific transactions, ensuring adherence to securities laws, AML, and KYC requirements.
Regulatory Considerations
While BWBs are designed to be transferable, their tradeability is subject to:
✔ SEC & CFTC regulations (if classified as securities or commodities).
✔ AML/KYC enforcement (restricted wallets cannot send or receive BWBs).
✔ Jurisdictional compliance (certain regions may impose additional restrictions).
Bottom Line
BWBs are legally enforceable, blockchain-based stablecoins backed by real water rights. They can be resold or transferred, but transactions are subject to:
✔ Regulatory compliance
✔ Ownership verification
✔ Automated enforcement mechanisms to prevent illicit activity or unauthorized transfers
Most importantly, nobody but you can spend your BWB tokens. This is guaranteed by the blockchain protocol, which requires the private spending key of the wallet owner to authorize any transaction—ensuring complete ownership security, similar to self-custodied Bitcoin.
To be perfectly clear, when we say “spend,” we mean both:
✔ Transferring BWBs from one wallet to another
✔ Redeeming BWBs for water at the source
We will never redeem BWBs for water without the private spending key’s authorization—ever.
Thus, while your BWBs can be frozen, they can never be transferred to another wallet or redeemed for water without your explicit permission.
This fundamental principle is what makes our water a true bearer instrument—ensuring absolute asset control for BWB holders.
4. Are BWBs Legal Tender or a Form of Payment?
No, BWBs are not legal tender, government-backed currency, or a form of money. Although they are fully compliant with AML and KYC regulations—which means there is no anonymity and they cannot be used in illicit activities—they are considered bearer instruments in the sense that any transaction requires the private spending key (similar to how Bitcoin operates). However, BWBs are not intended for use as a medium of exchange for goods, services, or debts. Instead, they function strictly as commodity-backed tokens that serve as digital records of a shareholder’s right to claim a specific quantity of water.
What BWBs Represent
Not Money or Banking Products
BWBs are not integrated into the traditional financial system. They do not function as currency, securities, or debt instruments and do not serve as spendable money in the way that fiat currency does.Commodity-Backed Ownership
BWBs are comparable to instruments such as carbon credits or physically settled futures contracts, where the value is directly tied to a tangible asset—in this case, water. They represent a fractional claim on water rights rather than an expectation of financial gain.Not a Medium of Exchange
BWBs cannot be used to settle debts or to purchase goods or services. Their sole purpose is to record and enforce ownership and redemption rights for water at the source.
How BWBs Work
Tokenized Water Rights
BWBs are digital tokens that represent fractional ownership of water rights. Each token entitles its holder to redeem a predetermined quantity of water, ensuring transparent and verifiable redemption rights.Blockchain-Based Security
BWBs employ blockchain technology to secure ownership records on an immutable ledger. This eliminates fraud and human interference, ensuring that only the holder with the private spending key can authorize transfers or redemptions.Regulatory Compliance
BWBs are designed to comply with all legal standards for commodity-backed ownership. By prioritizing regulatory adherence, they are structured solely as a water redemption mechanism, not as a form of money or a payment tool.
Key Takeaways
BWBs are not money; they do not function as currency or as banking products.
They are a blockchain-based system for redeeming water, with each token representing a claim on a specific quantity of water.
Ownership is secured exclusively by the blockchain, meaning that only the holder’s private spending key can authorize any transaction.
Final Note
BWBs have no connection to traditional banking, legal tender, or everyday financial transactions. They exist solely as a mechanism for redeeming water. Once redeemed, a token is permanently removed from circulation, ensuring that it serves purely as a claim on a tangible asset. In this regard, BWBs are no more “money” than SPDR Gold Shares (GLD) held in a brokerage account—they are simply less liquid and more volatile. Their value is derived entirely from their commodity backing rather than from functioning as a medium of payment.
7. Can BWBs be confiscated, frozen, or revoked by any authority?
This question reflects a misunderstanding of the nature of BWBs. They are fractional shares in mineral rights specifically tied to water extraction at the source—nothing more. BWBs themselves cannot be forcibly transferred, revoked, or confiscated. However, the digital wallets that hold these tokens can be blocked from spending or redeeming them if they are flagged for fraud, illicit activity, or regulatory violations.
As a responsible custodian, we will not redeem BWBs for water from a wallet associated with fraudulent activity. Without the private spending key, no one—not we, regulators, or financial institutions—can initiate a transaction, redeem a BWB, or transfer it to another wallet. This means that even if a wallet is blacklisted, only its rightful owner, regardless of any accusations or legal proceedings, retains control over their BWBs.
How BWB Freezing Works
Ownership Security
Only the holder of the private spending key can authorize any transaction involving BWBs. This ensures that no party—even we—can forcefully transfer or reassign them.Blocking Fraudulent Wallets
If a wallet is linked to criminal activity, designated custodian banks can blacklist it, preventing that wallet from redeeming BWBs for water or transferring them to another wallet. Furthermore, any wallet that receives BWBs from a blacklisted wallet without proper custodian oversight will itself be flagged and blacklisted. This network-wide measure helps ensure that illicit tokens remain frozen.Determining Fraudulent Activity
Decisions about whether a wallet is associated with fraudulent behavior are made by designated custodian banks or compliance authorities based on legal evidence in their jurisdiction. We do not control the blacklist; we simply enforce the restrictions imposed by these regulatory bodies and financial institutions.
Bottom Line
BWBs themselves cannot be confiscated, redeemed, revoked, or transferred by any authority—they always remain under the control of the private key holder. However, if a wallet is flagged for fraud or other regulatory issues, it can be blocked from redeeming or spending its BWBs, effectively freezing any tokens it holds. This process is managed by custodian banks and compliance authorities, ensuring due process and legal oversight. While any wallet may choose to self-custody, those that violate blacklist rules risk having their tokens frozen. In short, while BWBs offer robust self-custody protections, the compliance measures in place ensure that bad actors cannot misuse them—striking a balance between secure ownership and necessary regulatory enforcement.
8. How do BWBs differ from securities, stablecoins, or other digital assets?
BWBs are commodity-backed tokens that function much like PAXG (Paxos Gold), a gold-backed stablecoin redeemable for accredited gold bullion. Just as PAXG allows token holders to exchange their tokens for physical gold, BWBs guarantee the right to redeem a fixed quantity of water at its source.
However, there is a key difference: while many stablecoins—including PAXG—offer redemption options in both physical assets and fiat currency, BWBs are strictly limited to water redemption. They do not support any fiat-denominated obligations or monetary settlements; they exist solely as a means to claim a specific, tangible resource.
Additionally, BWBs are issued as Ethereum smart contracts, which ensures that all ownership records are transparent, immutable, and tamper-proof on the blockchain. Unlike many speculative digital assets, BWBs represent verifiable and legally enforceable water extraction rights, rather than an abstract or fluctuating financial value.
In summary, BWBs are distinct from securities and other digital assets in that they provide a direct, enforceable claim on a physical commodity (water) without functioning as a medium of exchange or a financial instrument.
9. What legal framework governs BWBs, and how are they regulated?
BWBs are primarily governed by New Hampshire state property law because they represent fractional mineral rights tied to water extraction at the source. In simple terms, the ownership rights for BWBs are determined by the same laws that apply to mineral rights in New Hampshire.
When it comes to compliance—specifically AML (Anti-Money Laundering) and KYC (Know Your Customer) measures—this isn’t something we handle directly. Instead, local, regulated custodians take care of these requirements. They ensure that all transactions follow the appropriate AML/KYC rules, maintain blacklists of problematic accounts, and decide which transactions are allowed based on local laws governing digital wallets and bank accounts.
Regulatory oversight varies from one jurisdiction to another. Each country or region applies its own rules based on where a wallet is registered, which means that local laws determine whether a wallet can accept transactions. While New Hampshire law governs the right to physically extract water from the source, other jurisdictions where BWBs are offered may impose additional restrictions. This multi-layered approach ensures that BWBs remain compliant with regulations around the world.
In short, BWBs are regulated primarily under New Hampshire property law as mineral rights, while local custodians manage compliance issues like AML/KYC enforcement and blacklisting. This setup allows each jurisdiction to enforce its own rules, with the U.S. (specifically New Hampshire) serving as the final authority on water redemption rights at the source, all while keeping BWBs fully compliant internationally.
10. How do BWBs handle AML/KYC compliance while maintaining self-custody protections?
BWBs use a two-signature system that ensures every transaction meets AML/KYC standards while allowing users to keep full control of their tokens. Each wallet contains two sets of keys: one for sending funds (the spending or debit key) and one for receiving funds (the receiving or credit key). For a transaction to be valid, both the sender and the receiver must digitally sign it; if either party fails to sign, the transaction will not occur.
When additional compliance is necessary, a wallet may opt to work with a regulated custodian—such as a bank—to approve incoming transactions. In this arrangement, the custodian checks that all transfers comply with local regulatory standards before processing them. If the custodian rejects a valid transaction, the result is simply a blocked transaction; the funds remain with the sender, and the wallet owner can choose another custodian or manage their wallet independently.
For those who prefer to self-custody their wallets without a custodian, there is an automatic safeguard against illicit activity: if a self-managed wallet receives funds from a blacklisted account, it will itself become blacklisted. Once blacklisted, that wallet will be unable to redeem BWBs for water, effectively freezing its tokens and discouraging illegal transactions.
In summary, BWBs achieve a balance between compliance and self-custody by requiring dual signatures for every transaction. Regulated custodians enforce AML/KYC rules when needed, yet users retain complete control over their wallets. Self-custody is still an option, but accepting funds from a blacklisted source will automatically result in the wallet being blacklisted. This approach ensures full regulatory compliance while preserving user control over their assets.
11. Can BWBs be used for investment purposes, or do they hold financial value?
No, BWBs are not meant to be investment vehicles and don't function like traditional financial assets. Their primary role is to control access to water at the source and to guarantee that water will be delivered as needed.
BWBs are strictly commodity-backed tokens. They are designed to give bottlers and commercial users secure access to a fixed quantity of water, which is delivered in standard FDA-approved stainless steel containers. The value of a BWB comes solely from its function as a claim on a tangible asset—water—not from any speculative investment or financial market activity.
Why someone might choose to hold water on demand—whether to resell it, bottle it, or use it in a hotel—is beyond our scope. Simply put, BWBs exist to ensure access to water, not to serve as an investment opportunity.
12. Can BWBs Be Traded or Have Resale Value?
Yes. BWBs are issued as ERC-20 compliant tokens, which means they can be traded on regulated secondary markets such as Coinbase—either in their native form or as wrapped tokens. Every transaction includes safeguards like dual-signature approvals and AML/KYC verification to ensure compliance with global financial regulations.
In the future, BWBs will transition to TNT (Transparent Network Technology), a purpose-built blockchain that offers lower transaction costs, enhanced regulatory adherence, and integrated smart contracts. This migration will not affect current ERC-20 trading; wrapped versions of BWBs will continue to be usable on Ethereum-based exchanges.
In short, BWBs have resale value and can be freely traded on compliant platforms, with their evolving structure designed to boost efficiency while preserving accessibility.
13. What Happens If a BWB Holder Loses Their Private Key?
If you use a custodian-backed wallet with KYC verification, losing your private key does not automatically mean permanent loss of your BWBs. In such cases, the custodian can blacklist the lost wallet to prevent unauthorized transactions and reissue your BWBs to a new wallet after verifying your identity. This recovery process helps ensure you regain access without compromising security.
On the other hand, if you self-custody your wallet without a custodian, losing your private key results in permanent loss of access—much like Bitcoin. This dual approach balances user control and regulatory compliance: verified custodial wallets provide a safety net, while self-custody offers full independence with inherent risks. Ultimately, the system is designed to safeguard assets while aligning with financial regulations through robust fraud prevention and recovery options.
14. How is Unauthorized Access to BWBs Prevented?
BWBs are secured using multiple layers of protection that leverage Ethereum's inherent security features. First, smart contracts enforce strict, tamper-proof rules for every transaction, and each transaction is permanently recorded on Ethereum’s public ledger. This ensures complete transparency and auditability while preventing any unauthorized changes.
Because the blockchain is decentralized, no single authority—even the issuer—can alter ownership rights or interfere with transactions. Additionally, BWBs require a dual-signature process, meaning both the sender and the receiver must approve every transaction. This extra step significantly reduces the risk of fraudulent transfers.
Regulated custodians further enhance security by enforcing AML and KYC protocols. They monitor wallet activity and blacklist any accounts that exhibit suspicious behavior. For those who self-custody their BWBs, if their wallet interacts with a blacklisted account, it is automatically flagged and blocked from further transactions or redemptions.
Together, these measures—immutable smart contracts, transparent auditing, decentralized control, dual-signature requirements, and rigorous compliance monitoring—create a robust system that effectively prevents fraud and unauthorized access while maintaining user control and regulatory adherence.